The logic of business networking is striking – at least to academics
who try to understand the determinants of corporate competitiveness. For
companies the logic is frequently quite different.
What is co-operation between firms?
Co-operation between firms typically involves three features which can
be analytically distinguished, namely relational contracting, information
exchange / joint learning, and collective action.
Relational contracting is the opposite of arms-length relationships.
Whereas the latter typically involve spot transactions, often based on
auctions or auction-like arrangements, relational contracting involves a
long-term business relationship. Arms-length relationships require
extensive legal dealings, whereas relational contracting is often based on
trust. Relational contracting occurs both within hierarchical settings
(for instance in supplier relationships in Japanese industry) and in
heterarchical environments (e.g. industrial districts).
Typical kinds of information exchange between firms include the
following:
- Informal information exchange between firms in
supplier/subcontracting arrangements, going beyond what is necessary
for arms-length transactions. The customer may give assistance to his
suppliers, e.g. how to work with certain new materials or how to deal
with quality problems. This may happen both among neighbouring firms
and within global supplier networks.
- Formal and informal information exchange between firms in strategic
alliances. There has been a strong increase in the number of national
and international strategic alliances between firms, i.e. co-operation
ventures aiming at the development of a given technology on the basis
of a contract. Behind this is the necessity to pool R&D resources
to reduce development lead-times and to realise synergies.
- Formal and informal information exchange between firms in business
associations. They often are a forum for technical discussions.
- Information exchange between firms' employees in professional
associations, which may be formal (e.g. presentations in conferences)
or informal (e.g. discussions during meetings and conferences).
Frequent types of collective action include the following:
- the provision of real services by business associations.
- jointly maintained, organisationally separate mesoinstitutions in
fields like training, technology information, or export information.
- political lobbying and active participation in forums which work on
shaping locational advantages.
In the real world, relational contracting, information exchange, and
collective action will often go hand-in-hand; in fact, all three types of
activities will reinforce each other, i.e. meetings in well-functioning
business associations open opportunities to informal information exchange,
and information exchange may reach barriers that can only be overcome
through collective action. Taken together, this leads to the emergence of
inter-firm networks.
top
Why firms may co-operate
In the view of institutional economics there are two major reasons why
firms co-operate, namely transaction costs and principal-agent problems in
arms-length relationships. Arms-length relationships require an elaborate
contract which is costly to set up, negotiate, and enforce, thus causing
high transaction costs. Principal-agent problems emerge to the extent
that, for instance, a subcontractor or supplier is contractually obliged
to employ certain process technologies but chooses a cheaper alternative,
and the principal contractor is not easily able to tell the difference
(for instance in surface treatment or chemical treatment of textiles).
Some co-operation arrangements (e.g. strategic alliances) may also involve
principal-agent-problems. Relational contracting and dense, long-term
networks may offer substantial benefits in terms of minimising transaction
costs and reducing principal-agent problems. Such arrangements are based
on mutual trust. Agreements are self-enforcing to the extent that firms
run the risk of eroding trust, and thus possibly drop out of the network,
if they behave opportunistically.
In the perspective of innovation economics, co-operation between firms
is a crucial feature since innovation is a cumulative process, involves
learning-by-doing, -using, and -interacting, and often yields increasing
returns. Particularly important is learning-by-interacting. There is both
an empirical and a theoretical argument behind the emphasis innovation
economics puts on learning-by-interacting. Behind the empirical argument
is the notion that the most frequent type of innovation, namely
incremental innovation, is not an event but a process of continuous
improvements. The process of incremental innovation takes up speed as a
development trajectory of a given technology becomes established, that is
as an increasing number of researchers and firms agree that a given
technology is preferable compared to other technologies. After this (often
implicit) agreement, two things happen. First, there is less uncertainty,
i.e. the risk that investment in R&D will have to be completely
written off because a given technology has to be dropped is minimised.
Second, an increasing number of researchers concentrate on improving a
given technology, and a mesolevel structure of research groups or
institutes, training courses and textbooks, norms and standards, etc. is
being created.
The theoretical argument addresses the issues of opportunity costs and
increasing returns. The alternative to inter-firm co-operation in
innovation would be an autarchy approach, i.e. each firm tries to go
through its own research effort and learning processes. In a certain way,
this occurs in the real world; it is usually referred to as the not-invented-here-syndrome.
This approach involves high opportunity costs as firms could have avoided
replication and repeating dead-end tracks by learning from the experience
of other firms.
In the view of innovation economics, the issue of transaction costs
involves the different forms learning-by-interacting can take. Formal
technology transfer, e.g. by licensing, is one of them. However, as the
use of technology implies a lot of tacit knowledge, no technology transfer
contract can define all the details that are involved; it can try to
define as many as possible, something that would be extremely costly in
terms of drafting, supervising and enforcing the contract. The alternative
is a combination of formal agreements and informal communication.
Moreover, there are other forms of technological learning based on
communication between firms, e.g. discussions in standardisation bodies or
at congresses. These mechanisms have low transaction costs.
Agreement between various actors -- firms, researchers, and others --
on a given technological trajectory can create the preconditions for
increasing returns. There are both increasing returns to scale due to a
large number of firms and researchers improving the same technology, i.e.
returns for the producers, and to adoption of a given technology, i.e.
returns for the users.
top
Why firms may not co-operate
Despite all its advantages, it is by no means self-evident that firms
co-operate. The advantages of co-operation may be obvious to innovation
economists and SME-support policy-makers, but many business-people do not
find them obvious at all, and for good reasons. Avoiding co-operation may
be perfectly rational behaviour. In our fieldwork we have found four main
reasons why entrepreneurs may choose go-it-alone as much as possible.
First, business-people often find the idea of co-operation repulsive
because they consider other firms in the same branch to be rivals, and one
would prefer not to communicate with them in order to avoid uncovering
business secrets.
Second, macroeconomic conditions may discourage inter-firm
co-operation. There may be high taxes on inter-firm transactions, thus
stimulating vertical integration. If the macroeconomic framework is
unstable and the "rules of the game" are constantly changing,
transactions between firms may be seen as isolated rather than repeated
prisoner's dilemmas, creating a situation where defaulting may appear as
an attractive option.
Third, even though co-operation can reduce transaction costs, it also
creates them. Co-ordinating a network often involves a substantial amount
of time to prepare meetings, to participate in them, and to take care of
the follow-up. Also, it is quite natural that conflicts will occur, and
resolving them again will require a lot of time and effort. Therefore,
there may be a discrepancy between the incentive for individual firms to
co-operate and the intensity of co-operation that would be desirable from
a macro perspective.
Fourth, there is the issue of the business culture and trust. In an
environment where firms are highly vertically integrated, where they stick
to themselves, where there have been occurrences of failed co-operation
ventures and predatory behaviour, a business culture arises that is
characterised by isolation and low trust. Both co-operation and
non-co-operation in a certain way result in increasing returns. In the
case of co-operation, successful joint ventures create more social
capital, thus improving the conditions for more co-operation. In the case
of non-co-operation, failed co-operative ventures strengthen the notion
that co-operation is impossible, thus undermining the prospects of success
of further efforts to stimulate co-operation. Both co-operation and
non-co-operation are thus path-dependent, with a particularly strong
lock-in effect in the case of non-co-operation as it is much easier to
destroy trust than distrust.
Against this background, the observation that clusters, i.e.
geographical concentrations of firms, do not necessarily mean dense
co-operation between firms does not come as a surprise. The emergence of
clusters is a ubiquitous phenomenon that is mainly due to the uneven
distribution of production factors, positive externalities, and historical
chance events. It is by no means a matter of course that co-operation
emerges within clusters. Whether is actually occurs, and which forms it
may take, depends on specific historical, local, institutional and
sub-sector circumstances. In the next section we look at distinct patterns
of co-operation in different types of industrial clusters in developing
countries.
See also: Promoting inter-firm co-operation
and Networking,
Business Contacts (first triangle: SME Promotion)
next chapter:
supporting institutions
last chapter:
business-friendly orientation of government
back
to: intangible factors for firms
top