Promoting inter-firm co-operation
In promoting inter-firm cooperation, it is important to distinguish
two consecutive steps. The first step is to get firms involved in a
cooperation effort, i.e. to overcome their hostility against any sharing
of information and experiences. The second step is to mount a sustained
exercise of interaction and collective learning.
Starting with the first step, one should not
- assume that there exists firms’ demand for support, based on
common understanding or surveys. A survey may find that lack of
cooperation is one of the main reasons for low competitiveness.
However, firms will often have a profoundly different perception.
- take the analysis of key problems provided by the firms themselves
too serious. Firms will often see problems everywhere except
internally.
- overestimate the willingness of businessowners to start a joint
learning effort with other businessowners, particularly of the same
branch.
Accordingly, the traditional approach – prepare an analysis of
firms' problems and start to offer them certain services – is
inadequate. Moreover, starting an effort that has stimulating inter-firm
cooperation as its aim does not make much sense. Inter-firm cooperation
is a means of enhancing competitiveness, not an aim in its own right.
Rather, the first step should be to define, in an exercise that involves
businesspeople and support agencies (which need not be government
agencies!), the key bottlenecks that firms are facing, and to identify
those bottlenecks that can be remedied in the short term. This process
should aim at mobilizing the knowledge of all the firms involved, i.e.
stimulate inter-firm cooperation as a side effect. Promising areas are,
for instance, environmental issues like wastewater treatment and
treatment of waste, or training issues. These areas do not touch
directly on what firms perceive as there core competence so that there
will be less fear of giving away industrial secrets and more willingness
to cooperate.
Regarding the second step, the crucial issue is to find a way of
transforming the local business culture on a sustained basis. Business
associations may play a key role here as they are by definition the
place where cooperation between firms should take place. In the past,
however, they were often merely vehicles for policy entrepreneurs or
social clubs rather than effective entities. Technical assistance to
promote inter-firm cooperation should therefore target business
associations. The aim should be to encourage and accompany
organizational development processes in these
organizations. In fact, the conditions to do this may not be bad in
those locations where firms are under an increasing competitive
pressure. In some places, associations have entered into a virtuous
circle: By offering assistance to struggling firms, they have created an
incentive for voluntary, paying membership, thus increasing their
funding base. This in turn made it possible to widen the scope for
assistance to firms, again widening the funding base, and so on.
Such initiatives are most likely to succeed which meet four criteria:
- they address immediate problems of firms,
- they do not touch what firms perceive as their core activities,
- they open little or no latitude for predatory behavior,
- they offer the potential of savings through economies of scale.
Let me explain these criteria by briefly outlining typical activities
which do not meet them and usually fail. First, there is technological
co-operation, such as the joint development of a new production process.
In such a case, participating firms fear that other firms get to know
pieces of information which they perceive as essential to their
competitiveness. Accordingly, they put pressure on their technicians not
to unveil any possibly critical information, what in effect means that
it is unlikely that the co-operation project gets anywhere. Firms may
also choose their less competent technicians to take part in the
project, something that also does not enhance the probability of
success. Second, when one mentions the option of co-operation,
businesspeople in a non-cooperative cluster typical come up first of all
with ideas which effectively are anti-competitive, such as forming a
purchasing co-operative. However, if firms do not trust each other, a
supplier who is the target of the co-operative will easily break it by
offering preferential purchasing conditions to one or some of the
participating firms.
What then are activities which meet the four criteria? Research in
clusters in the state of Santa Catarina, Brazil (Meyer-Stamer 1998)
found three types of activities:
- Training. Even though surprisingly many firms opted for
in-house training (even when it came to basic education for
semi-literate employees), there were numerous examples of joint
training activities. The economies of scale are obvious, the
benefits as well, there is little option for predatory behavior, and
the training is limited to areas which do not touch upon the core
activities.
- Environment-related activities. In this area co-operation
between firms involved a level of exchange of information between
firms which was unthinkable in areas such as quality management or
technological development. Apart from being due to the fact that
firms, initially mostly sticking to end-of-pipe-solutions, perceived
environmental protection literally as a peripheral activity, the
fact that there was the government environmental agency as an
external enemy also created an incentive to stick together.
- Basic testing activities. In the textiles industry this
refers to testing cotton fibers and chemical inputs, in the ceramic
tile industry to testing the clay. In fact, in the ceramic tile
cluster around Criciúma, which is the leading cluster in the
industry in Latin America, it was after a major crisis in the early
1990s that firms lobbied their business association and state
government to create a technology center which had testing as one of
its main activities. The crisis forced firms to look out for
potentials to save costs. Before that, each firm had its own
laboratory.
Looking at the evolution of the clusters in Santa Catarina, it is
possible to perceive that initiatives like those just mentioned may pave
the way for more ambitious co-operation activities. As firms see that
co-operation creates advantages, they may develop a certain degree of
trust which permits other, more ambitious and risky co-operation
activities, such as exchange of technological information. However,
there is by no means a clear trajectory in this respect. The experience
of the tile cluster in Criciúma is somewhat sobering: After a massive
joint effort to deal with the crisis achieved most of its declared goals
by the mid-1990s, the degree of co-operation has been decreasing again.
Whereas four years ago several of the local actors saw their cluster on
track to emulate the experience of Italian industrial districts, today
one can sense a certain frustration which may be due to the fact that
maintaining co-operation is quite an effort.
back
to: business networking
top