Financial systems and instruments
|
More... |
The attractiveness of tangible locational factors
depends to a large degree on the financial scope of manoeuvre at
disposal on the side of the local authorities. The larger the financial
resources, the higher is the potential for local governments to invest
in local infrastructure and raise locational attraction. The question
is, how this may be achieved, what are the financial instruments at hand
for local authorities?
Central government transfers
In most of the developing countries, financial
transfers from central government to subnational levels of government
account for the dominant source of local revenue. Technically, there are
different forms of transfers:
-
Matching transfers require local governments to
come up with a share of the funding of its own. This means that
without a financial contribution of the community, central
government will not release the money. This is to spur resource
mobilization efforts by the community itself and avoid an attitude
of dependency on part of the local governments towards the centre.
-
Nonmatching transfers offer a given amount of
funds without any complementary funding by local governments. Some
of these are conditional, meaning that they can be spent for
specific purposes only, whereas others are unconditional, with no
constraints being put on the way it is spent.
At first glance, transfers from central government
appear to be the easiest way to guarantee a flow of money to the local
treasurer. However, with the rare exception of unconditional nonmatching
transfers, the administrative procedures for accessing and reporting on
their use are often cumbersome. Sometimes, for example, accounting
procedures need to be changed, expenditures reclassified, special
accounts have to be set up, and so forth. All this raises local
administrative costs and uses up scarce resources.
In more general terms, grants may also serve as a
sweet poison and undermine efforts and abilities to mobilize local
resources.
top
Local taxes
By assigning local taxes, local governments are
mobilizing local resources and thus become more independent from
superior powers donating money to them. In most developing countries
where there is a legislation on decentralization, local communities are
attributed the right to assign local taxes. In doing so, one has to
follow certain principles in order to really achieve the objective of
local resource mobilization:
-
No strangulation of the local economy: The
tax rates need to be carefully determined. Whereas minor or petty
tax rates would not result in sufficiently high tax volumes, high
rates might pose a heavy burden on the local business community and
produce a slowing down of local economic growth. A golden path in
the middle needs to be found.
-
Try to mix taxes: If one introduced only,
say, a single tax, the tax burden would be confined to a specific
group (for example the consumers, the salaried people, property
owners). This is socially unfair, because most of the gains of local
resource mobilization are open to the whole community, thus
producing benefits also for those who did not contribute anything.
Apart from this, the dependency on a single tax raises the
vulnerability of the local government towards the ups and downs of a
specific sector. Therefore, it is better to broaden the tax base and
introduce a mix of different sources of revenue.
-
Transparency: It is important to
demonstrate to local taxpayers for which purposes the money is
spent. This will heighten credibility with the electorate and will
make it easier in case any future changes in tax assignments will
become necessary.
-
Consider administrative costs: Collection
procedures should be as simple as possible in order not to waste
scarce resources on administration and to retain a larger part for
investment purposes. Take the so-called informal sector as an
example. If you tried to assign an income tax as a percentage of a
person's monthly or annual income, you would encounter innumerable
difficulties to assess it somehow correctly. Using a nominal flat
rate adjusted from time to time to the inflation rate would very
much facilitate tax collection.
-
Cooperate with neighbouring municipalities:
Often, neighbouring municipalities try to get a competitive
advantage over one another by offering lower tax rates. They enter
into a downward spiral as far as the rates are concerned, which,
from a certain point onwards, produces negative results for the
whole group of local areas. Cooperation between local areas can
avoid this kind of hazardous rivalry.
Having given an overview of the principles that should
rule the assignment of local sources of revenue, the question now arises
what kind of taxes are more suitable for local assignment:
-
The individual income tax is considered by
fiscal experts as a good choice for local governments. The burden of
this tax would normally be borne by the beneficiaries - the local
residents - of local government spending. There are cases that allow
for an easy administration of this tax, especially in cases where
local governments can opt for an add-on to the central government
tax rate.
-
The property tax is seen as a very
appropriate source of local government revenue, because it is
visible and allows for a relatively easy identification and
verification by local assessors. It is also difficult to export
property and evade the tax. Apart from this, it is also a tax on
wealth and thus serves certain redistributive objectives. On the
other hand, experience shows that the property tax alone does not
produce sufficient revenue.
-
Motor vehicles are considered another good
source of revenue. The taxation of motor fuels, licenses, tolls and
parking taxes are all considered being administratively feasible.
The motor fuel tax offers the greatest potential for income, but
very often central governments depend heavily on this source and
would not easily share this cake with local governments.
Other taxes, such as the value added tax or the
corporate income taxes are not considered good choices for local
governments, as difficulties with international trade (zero-rated in the
case of the value added tax) and with equity considerations may occur
(if, for example, one municipality is the home of a big company that is
an excellent tax payer, whereas other local areas in the neighbourhood
do not have this privilege and therefore stay poor).
top
User charges
Charging the users for services offered by the local
administration is another source of revenues. They may be charged for
services related to "tangible" factors such as wastewater
treatment, refuse disposal, real estate development and the provision of
transport infrastructure as well as for "intangible" factors
such as kindergardens, leisure facilities and local educational
institutions.
Ideally, fees should be charged that cover at least the production costs
of these services. This is easily said but in practice difficult to
implement. In order to create a locational advantage, a local government
might be tempted to offer high-quality services at a low price. This may
be advantageous in the short-run but in the long-run, if the deficit in
these operations is bridged by commercial borrowing, the debts incurred
may in result in high debt-service payments limiting the financial scope
of manoeuvre of the local administration enormously. In general, it
might be more promising in the long run to achieve cost-recovery
(including maintenance costs) in the operation of these services.
Long-term stability and quality in the provision of services is more
rewarding than short-term competitive advantages.
top
Borrowing
Borrowing capital is, at least ideally, another option
for local governments. Borrowing is especially important when it comes
to financing larger capital investments. The benefits of such
investments often last several decades and it seems only fair to let
future generations also participate in its financing (via interest
payments that last for decades as well). Another purpose for borrowing
is the bridging of gaps between tax intakes and expenditures incurred.
However, very often there is the danger of avoiding any sort of reform
when the gap is not of temporary but of structural nature. Politicians
are tempted to seek an easy way out of financial imbalances by resorting
to borrowing, thus deepening these financial difficulties.
In principle, there are three different channels to
source:
-
central government borrowing from the national
central bank and on-lending to subnational tiers,
-
borrowing through a public intermediary such as a
state-owned financial institution and
-
direct borrowing from capital markets.
In poor countries, local governments do usually not
have the possibility of borrowing money from capital markets, as they
very often do not dispose of the necessary guarantees and because
capital markets are not developed.
Rural Finance (agricultural lending, non-farm rural
lending, deposit services in rural areas)
One of the main activity areas of financial systems development in
the recent past has been the development of financial systems and
instruments for rural regions. Efforts were undertaken to identify those
policies, practices, strategies and capacity building
measures which need to be taken into account to ensure that rural
populations have better access to effective financial services. These
instruments aim at creating an awareness among governments, private
sector and international development and donor agencies, of the need to
apply appropriate policies and to set required rules of conduct.
More of
Financial Systems:
last chapter: real estate information
development
back to: tangible locational factors
top