Regional Economic Promotion (REP) Approaches in
Chile
A summary of lessons learnt
Regional economic promotion (REP) means a change from
a sectoral to a territorial approach in economic promotion. For many
people, this is a new and unfamiliar approach and requires time and
effort to familiarize themselves with. Another issue is access to
reliable and detailed data. Often, regional and local development
potentials can only be seen on the background of new or better
information. Thus, Chilean projects usually strive for two things:
first, joint endeavours among municipalities, local stakeholders and
government support institutions in the beginning of REP initiatives;
second, creating new visions and perspectives and an adequate
information base in order to allow for strategic planning.
Local and regional authorities are often not prepared
in matters of effective local economic development policy.
Methodological knowledge about data collection, data analysis and
participatory planning methods is rare. To ensure effectiveness of the
REP approach, it is most important to get all relevant stakeholders to
actually participate in meetings, conferences and workshops.
Municipalities, provincial and regional governments
must also be enabled to link strategic planning with existing obligatory
regional planning, spatial planning, land use planning and site planning
procedures.
Institutional demarcations of political and
administrative entities such as municipalities, provinces and regions
are not always congruent with economic networks and linkages. If,
however, support for genuine economic regions is the objective, this
needs to be kept in mind when local stakeholders for local and regional
economic promotion are rallied. Experience showed that activities
grounded in genuine economic regions had quicker and more significant
success.
Municipalities were willing to contribute in cash and
kind when they were able to see the scope of action widened for local
decision makers and when development perspectives were clear. This
contributes to improved ownership in the municipalities and increases
significance and outreach of activities.
All measures aiming at strengthening political
capacities of municipalities, provinces and regions have to be rooted in
an analysis of the present institutional setting. From this point of
view, it is evident that regional authorities presently hardly profit
from entrepreneurial activities in their territories. Apart from
positive effects on the labour market and income situation (which differ
widely locally according to investment and sector), municipalities and
regions are hardly or not at all benefiting from tax income. This
contributes to centralizing tendencies in enterprise structure,
aggravates the intensification of local value chains and prevents
quality oriented competition between locations. Decentralisation of
income has to be matched with decentralisation of public investment .
Decentralisation is taking place in Chile but in a
hesitant manner and without a consistent overarching concept of
institutional modernisation. Nevertheless, it has led to networks of
local stakeholders with a structure-inducing effect in municipalities
and regions. On the background of this development, the legislative
process seems to be particularly backward. The reason for this is that
central government political protagonists (congress, political parties
and the majority of ministries in particular) do not perceive the
dynamics of institutional change, or they interpret it as a zero-sum
game from which they will finally evolve as losers. This shows that
decentralisation in Chile is different from decentralisation processes
in other Latin American countries. While constitutional reforms marked
the beginning of the process and political practice followed (decentralisation
top-down) in Brazil, Bolivia, Venezuela and Colombia, major political
decisions in Chile are taking place before legislative or even
constitutional activities occur (decentralisation bottom-up). This does
not mean that one way is better than the other but either way has
important implications for the consultancy process in institutional
modernisation.
In times of institutional change there is often
something happening like a redundancy of institutions which may
aggravate the actual efficiency of political governance mechanisms.
However, this redundancy also has positive effects: it makes competition
between different approaches and solutions possible which will broaden
adaptive options and chances in society in the long run. A development
model which invites this kind of competition and does not count on
one-dimensional institutional solutions for the sake of short-term
efficiency is thus more favourable to learning processes in society.
Recommendations:
REP addresses economic regions. As they do not always
coincide with administrative borders of provinces or regions or even
nations, other solutions have to be found. In cases of high
heterogeneity, it may be possible to support cooperation between
municipalities of similar or complementary structures.
Integrating the whole business range: where they
exist, medium and large businesses should also be supported in order to
strengthen their linkages with the local economy. They should be invited
to participate in strategic development planning right from the
beginning. Institutions of enterprise and export promotion or
(vocational) training institutions are other potential partners in
cooperation.
Incentive structures and promoters: the question of
incentive structures is at the center of institutional modernization. If
municipalities and regions are supposed to be strengthened effectively
as promoters of regional and local economic promotion, they need to
partake in entrepreneurial success in their respective localities, above
all through shares from the tax income. Furthermore, their autonomy in
programme implementation and in budget policy also needs to be enhanced.
The shifting of competencies in resource allocation needs to be
paralleled by fiscal decentralisation.
Planning competence and information processing
capacities: planning competencies of municipalities need to be
strengthened in order to achieve a viable connection between strategic
visions and public investment decisions. Municipalities often dispose
neither of institutional capacities nor of necessary information for
autonomous spatial planning and land use planning to channel public
investment and attract private investment. Experiences in Chile show
that local stakeholders tend to be overwhelmed by the dynamics of local
change. Serious information deficits on the local level with regard to
new promotional and budgetary instruments and scope of action are
common. Sometimes, information exists about certain areas of economic,
social or demographic development but there is no organisation to
collect and update these data. Information processing capacities are
therefore important in regional economic promotion.
REP as a cross cutting task and strengthening of meso
level institutions: Local and regional economic promotion are typical
cross-cutting tasks touching all competence levels of the political
system (nation, region, municipality) A core area for capacity building
is the institutional design of the meso level in the political and
administrative system. The REP approach represents a profound change
from a centrally managed supply-oriented policy to a policy of
decentralised, proactive voicing of needs. This implies the necessity of
leaving the respective programmes open to initiatives and innovations of
regional and local stakeholders and of strengthening institutions that
effectively carry out mediating functions between the local level and
central government institutions. It is also essential to supplement
local level activities through institutional modernisation and political
consultancy on higher levels of the political system to ensure that
local successes will be firmly rooted on a broad institutional basis.
From that perspective, strengthening of the internal evaluation and
monitoring capacities of meso level institutions becomes important. In
addition, those national level structures should be supported in the
process of administrative decentralisation that facilitate the
evaluation of good REP practices in the regions and make them available
to other regions.
This study is based on an evaluation of 7 projects
dealing with local economic development issues (5 GTZ, 2 FES). It was
compiled by Christian von Haldenwang (DIE).
top